
Bork’s Failed Antitrust Philosophy
Lucas BennettBork’s Failed Antitrust Philosophy
Robert Bork’s influential work in antitrust law, particularly his 1978 book The Antitrust Paradox, reshaped how the United States approaches corporate mergers and monopolies. Bork argued that antitrust laws should prioritize economic efficiency, particularly lower prices for consumers, over concerns about market competition and the preservation of small businesses. His philosophy centered on the idea that if a merger resulted in lower consumer prices or greater efficiencies, it should be approved—regardless of the potential reduction in market competition. This approach has since been adopted in various antitrust decisions and shaped U.S. economic policy for decades.
However, while Bork’s theory promised that consolidation would lead to greater efficiencies, the real-world consequences often not matched his predictions. Many of the mergers approved under this philosophy have led to negative outcomes for consumers, including higher prices, reduced choices, and lower service quality. In this article, we will explore Bork’s antitrust philosophy, its widespread adoption, and the failure of his predictions using several notable merger examples.
Bork’s Antitrust Philosophy: The Focus on Economic Efficiency
Bork’s central thesis was that antitrust enforcement should be based on a clear and simple metric: consumer welfare. He argued that the goal of antitrust laws was not to preserve competition for its own sake, but to ensure that consumers benefit from lower prices, higher quality, and more innovation. This focus on price reductions was grounded in the idea that larger companies—if properly managed—could achieve economies of scale, reduce costs, and pass on those savings to consumers.
Under Bork’s framework, mergers between large corporations should be assessed based on whether they create efficiencies that lower prices for consumers. If a merger could prove that it would lower prices or increase efficiency in the market, it would be justified even if it led to reduced competition. In practice, this meant that mergers between companies could be approved as long as they resulted in cost-saving benefits that were presumed to trickle down to consumers.
This view was radical at the time and marked a significant departure from earlier antitrust thinking, which focused more on preserving competition and preventing monopolies. For example, under previous administrations, mergers were often blocked if they resulted in the creation of a monopoly or a significant reduction in competition, even if they promised lower prices. Bork’s philosophy fundamentally altered the way courts and regulators assessed these mergers, focusing more on potential efficiencies than on competitive fairness.
The Shift Toward Mergers and Market Consolidation
Bork’s influence on antitrust policy was profound. By the 1980s, his philosophy had gained widespread acceptance, and it became a cornerstone of U.S. antitrust enforcement. Under both Republican and Democratic administrations, regulators increasingly embraced Bork’s ideas, approving mergers that promised greater efficiencies, often at the expense of market competition. As a result, a wave of corporate consolidation swept across industries, as companies merged to achieve economies of scale and dominate markets.
In many cases, these mergers were presented as a way to reduce prices for consumers by eliminating inefficiencies. However, the outcomes of these mergers have often contradicted Bork’s predictions. Instead of benefiting consumers, many of these deals led to market concentration, higher prices, fewer choices, and reduced innovation.
Case Study 1: AT&T and Time Warner (2018)
The merger of AT&T and Time Warner was approved in 2018 with the promise that the combined company would result in more efficient services and lower prices for consumers. AT&T argued that the merger would allow it to better compete with tech giants like Google and Amazon by offering bundled packages of content and telecommunications services. The company claimed that the merger would lead to cost savings, which would ultimately be passed on to consumers in the form of lower prices.
However, the reality was far from the promise. The merger allowed AT&T to control both content creation (through its ownership of Time Warner's media assets like HBO) and content distribution (through its telecommunications infrastructure). This consolidation of power gave AT&T the ability to charge higher prices for consumers who wanted access to popular shows and movies, and to bundle content in ways that limited customer choice. Far from lowering prices, the merger led to higher cable and streaming subscription fees, disproportionately affecting lower-income consumers who could least afford the rising costs. The predicted efficiencies failed to materialize, and consumers were left with higher prices and fewer choices.
Case Study 2: American Airlines and US Airways (2013)
The merger between American Airlines and US Airways was approved with the argument that it would create efficiencies by reducing costs, which would then be passed on to consumers. The airlines argued that by merging, they could better compete with other major carriers, like Delta and United, and improve service for customers.
However, after the merger, the expected benefits never materialized. Instead of lower ticket prices, consumers saw price increases, particularly on domestic flights. A report from the Government Accountability Office (GAO) found that airfare prices increased by 3-7% following the merger, as competition in key markets was reduced. The combined airline now had fewer incentives to lower prices or improve services, leading to a situation where consumers faced higher prices and fewer options. The merger’s promised efficiencies failed to benefit the average traveler.
Case Study 3: Exxon and Mobil (1999)
The merger between Exxon and Mobil in 1999 was approved by the Federal Trade Commission (FTC) with the argument that the consolidation would lead to greater efficiency in the oil and gas industry, ultimately benefiting consumers through lower prices. However, the result was the opposite: The merger allowed ExxonMobil to dominate the global oil market, consolidating power in a way that made it more difficult for smaller competitors to compete.
Rather than seeing lower prices, consumers experienced higher fuel costs at the pump. The combined company, with its market power, had less incentive to reduce prices, and consumers were left paying more for gasoline and other petroleum-based products. The ExxonMobil merger, like many others, demonstrated that consolidation in a crucial industry often results in price hikes, not reductions, as the newly formed monopoly is able to dictate prices without facing significant competition.
Case Study 4: Comcast and NBCUniversal (2011)
When Comcast merged with NBCUniversal in 2011, regulators approved the deal based on the argument that it would create efficiencies and improve service by allowing Comcast to offer more content options to consumers. The merger was seen as a way to streamline operations and reduce costs, which could theoretically benefit consumers.
Instead, the merger led to higher prices and fewer options. Comcast, already one of the largest cable providers in the U.S., now controlled not only the distribution of cable services but also a significant portion of the content (via NBCUniversal). This concentration of power allowed Comcast to raise prices for cable and internet subscriptions and limit access to NBCUniversal content for competing distributors. Consumers were forced to accept higher fees and fewer options for content, as the merger stifled competition in the cable and media industries.
Case Study 5: T-Mobile and Sprint (2020)
The merger between T-Mobile and Sprint was approved in 2020, with the argument that it would lead to greater efficiencies and better service by combining the third and fourth-largest wireless carriers in the U.S. The companies promised that the merger would accelerate the rollout of 5G networks and ultimately benefit consumers with faster service and lower prices.
However, critics argued that the merger would reduce competition in the wireless market, leading to higher prices in the long run. While T-Mobile has made some progress in expanding 5G coverage, the merger’s effect on pricing has been less positive. Many consumers have reported price increases, particularly in low-cost plans, and fewer options in certain markets. By consolidating the two carriers, the merger created a less competitive environment, with fewer incentives for price reduction.
The Failure of Bork’s Philosophy
The legacy of Robert Bork’s antitrust philosophy, which emphasized economic efficiency and lower prices as the sole metric for evaluating mergers, has proven to be flawed. While the theory suggested that consolidation would lead to lower prices and benefits for consumers, in practice, it has often resulted in higher prices, less choice, and reduced competition. The examples of AT&T and Time Warner, American Airlines and US Airways, Exxon and Mobil, Comcast and NBCUniversal, and T-Mobile and Sprint all illustrate how corporate consolidation, under the guise of efficiency, can harm consumers by limiting competition and driving up costs.
Bork’s focus on consumer welfare, as defined by price reductions, missed a key point: the importance of maintaining competitive markets to drive innovation, improve service quality, and ensure fair pricing. At best Bork obtusely distilled a complex topic down to too narrow a focus. He also failed at accurately predicting the results within that narrow view. At worst, he intentionally paved the way for corporations to consolidate market power by simply promising to use their new power for “good.” By playing along with Bork and allowing mergers that reduced competition, regulators inadvertently set the stage for monopolistic behavior that benefited large corporations at the expense of the average consumer. As we move forward, it is essential to reconsider the narrow view of antitrust enforcement that Bork promoted and recognize that true consumer welfare is about more than just price—it is about ensuring that markets remain competitive and that all Americans have access to affordable goods and services.